ABUL RIZVI: Why 5% unemployment today is not the same as 5% unemployment 10-20 years ago

The unemployment rate, and even the underemployment rate, have become an inadequate measure of the true health of our labour market.

When unemployment increased to over 11 percent in 1992-93, we worried but were not surprised given the state of the economy. After all, our unemployment rate was over 10 percent just ten years earlier after the 1982-83 recession and we experienced similar levels of unemployment in the 1974-75 recession.

So when unemployment fell to less than 5 percent in 2006-2008, Australians enjoyed boom times with real wages rising rapidly and a strongly growing economy. It was a time we worried about high interest rates. John Howard promised us interest rates would always be lower under a Coalition Government – a boast he may no longer wish to be repeated.

It was also a time net overseas migration was rising rapidly compared to each of the three recessions mentioned above. Net overseas migration fell sharply during each of our three major recessions of the past 50 years to levels around 50,000 and lower. Net overseas migration also fell after the Global Financial Crisis (when Australia did not fall into recession) but not nearly as far as it fell during the three major recessions (see data.gov.au for historical migration statistics).

With the unemployment rate falling to 5.1 percent in December 2019, a trend participation rate just below our record level of 66.1 percent and net overseas migration still at relatively high levels, why isn’t our economy booming again?

This question has been the subject of much debate including the fact that a 5 percent unemployment rate today is not really the same as a 5 percent unemployment rate 20 or even 10 years ago.

But how can that be? Hasn’t the definition of unemployment remained the same?

The unemployment rate measures the portion of people participating in the labour force who do not have a job. Of course people in employment are defined as anyone with a job even if it is only for one hour a week. If the portion of people with a job that employs them for only a few hours per week is significantly higher today than was the case 10 or 20 years ago, the unemployment rate would no longer be comparing like with like.

That would certainly be the case if more people are working as casuals or part-time or indeed in the gig economy. The ABS seeks to measure this effect by adding underemployment to unemployment to measure what it calls the underutilisation rate. It defines underemployment as “people employed part time who wanted to work more hours and were available to start work with more hours”.

But this remains a subjective measure of what people would like to have.

A better, more objective measure of the state of the labour market would be the average number of hours actually worked per month per adult.

Apart from being an objective measure, it also incorporates the impact of unemployment, participation, underemployment and population ageing.

In that sense it is a measure that is more readily comparable over time than the unemployment rate.

Chart 1 below tracks this measure for the last 40 years.

It clearly highlights the impact of the 1982-83 recession when average hours worked per month per adult fell to 95.4 and the 1992-93 recession when it fell to 98.9.

Source: ABS Cat: 6202 and 3101

After peaking at 108.1 in June 2008, it fell sharply after the Global Financial Crisis to 103.6, recovering only briefly in 2010 and 2011, largely due to the Government’s fiscal stimulus.

It has been in slow and steady decline ever since. By June 2019 it had reached 99.7. The first time in 40 years it has been below 100 outside a recession.

Source: ABS Population Projections, Cat: 3222, Series B

How should we interpret that decline?

It clearly confirms the fact our current economy and labour market are weak. The Government’s crowing about the number of jobs created is largely a reflection of the level of net overseas migration – which by the way is now falling and well below the 2019 Budget forecast.

But does it also reflect the fact Australia’s working age to population ratio peaked around 2008-09 and has been declining ever since (see Chart 2).

If it is, amongst other factors, a reflection of the impact of population ageing, will this indicator continue to deteriorate. There will undoubtedly be periods in the future when the economy strengthens and the average number of hours worked per month per adult will rise.

The impact of ageing, however, will be relentless.

It is time we once again started to think about how we are going to manage our economy and our society with an ageing population.

We can take comfort in the fact our population will not age as rapidly as most other developed countries, particularly countries in Europe as well as in East Asia (ie Japan, China, Korea). See Chart 3 for a comparison of our rate of ageing with that of Japan.

Source: ABS cat 3222 and Statistics Bureau of Japan

Australia will age more slowly predominantly because of our immigration program.

However, as an economy heavily dependent on international trade, it would be a mistake to think we will be immune from the impact of population ageing.

Treasurer Josh Frydenberg has the opportunity in the next Inter-Generational Report due in May this year to lay out a plan for how Australia will manage the impact of ageing.

He could squib the challenge by repeating the fantasies in his 2019 ten year budget plan. Or he could be honest with us and give us a genuine plan for our future.

Abul Rizvi was a senior official in the Department of Immigration from the early 1990s to 2007 when he left as Deputy Secretary. He was awarded the Public Service Medal and the Centenary Medal for services to development and implementation of immigration policy, including in particular the reshaping of Australia’s intake to focus on skilled migration. He is currently doing a PhD on Australia’s immigration policies.

Abul Rizvi PhD was a senior official in the Department of Immigration from the early 1990s to 2007 when he left as Deputy Secretary. He was awarded the Public Service Medal and the Centenary Medal for services to development and implementation of immigration policy, including the reshaping of Australia’s intake to focus on skilled migration, slow Australia’s rate of population ageing and boost Australia’s international education and tourism industries.

Comments

4 responses to “ABUL RIZVI: Why 5% unemployment today is not the same as 5% unemployment 10-20 years ago”

  1. Marcus L'Estrange Avatar
    Marcus L’Estrange

    What about the million unemployed who are not counted because they didn’t apply for non existent jobs? Many of these already have their resumes listed with potential employers or have a short term health problem or simply have different skills to those required.

  2. Wayne McMillan Avatar
    Wayne McMillan

    When we talk about employment/unemployment we must mention discouraged unemployment and the growth in precarious employment. These two features of the current Australian Labour market are growing and their impact on wages growth are influential. Employers have the whip hand with growing short term part-time employment contracts and a reserve army of partially unemployed workers. To make matters worse, with the decline in the private sector union membership and union coverage of workplaces, employers have the perfect storm to dictate wages and working conditions.
    Workers have had to resort to credit card debt to maintain a decent standard of living, but this can’t last much longer as the economy slips into recession. Workers are retiring some of that household debt and their capacity to spend is being greatly reduced.

    1. michael lacey Avatar
      michael lacey

      Yes definitely needed to be mentioned!

      A feature of the neoliberal strategy for over 40 years has been the success

      The whole neoliberal trend in macroeconomic policy. The essential thing underlying this is to try to reduce the power of government and social forces that might exercise some power within the political economy—workers and and others—and put the power primarily in the hands of those dominating in the markets. That’s often the financial system, the banks, but also other elites. The idea of neoliberal economists and policymakers being that you don’t want the government getting too involved in macroeconomic policy. You don’t want them promoting too much employment because that might lead to a raise in wages and, in turn, to a reduction in the profit share of the national income.

      So, sure, this might increase inflation, but inflation is not really the key issue here. The problem, in their view, is letting the central bank support other kinds of policies that are going to enhance the power of workers, they want to put power in the hands of those who dominate the markets, often the financial elites.

      1. Charles Lowe Avatar

        I could hardly agree more with your perspective, Michael Lacey.

        Thank you.